
The Accidental Bookseller
Specializing in Uncommon Copies of Interesting Books
Membership(s): IOBA, FABA
Olajuwon, Hakeem
Living the Dream My Life and Basketball
$300.00
Olajuwon, Hakeem
Little, Brown & Co.: Boston, 1996. First edition.
Signed by Olajuwon and inscribed to his team mate Kenny Smith. Olajuwon and Smith played together on the back-to-back champion Houston Rockets. A stand out center, Olajuwon was a member of the 1994 US Dream Team, was selected as one of the 50 greatest players in NBA history and was named to the NBA 75th Anniversary Team.
Fine copy. Dust wrapper with one inch tear to bottom rear else fine.
The collaboration between Olajuwon and Smith began on a rocky note with tensions stemming from Smith giving his superstar teammate a bold warning soon after joining the Rockets:
“Akeem, if you ever scream at me like you have to other point guards, I will never throw you the ball,” Smith reportedly said.
Any teammate who said something like that to the legendary Olajuwon would likely have upset the reigning All-Star. But hearing it from a newly joined player was just too much. Frustrated, “The Dream” responded firmly, saying Smith would continue passing him the ball, no matter what.
However, “The Jet” stood his ground, replying with a firm “no.” While this might seem like an audacious move from the former 6’3″ playmaker, Smith actually had a strategic purpose. According to Miriam Fader’s book, he believed he needed to establish his credibility and “gain Olajuwon’s respect” early in their relationship.
If one trusts the reports about “The Dream” at the time, this actually seemed like the right approach. After all, the 1994 MVP had a reputation for being overly tough on point guards — a reputation that Kenny had also heard about — with many rumors circulating about Hakeem’s intense interactions with them.
Some stories describe him loudly “screaming” at point guards for mistakes, even demanding coaches “take them out on the spot.”Another account mentions a heated confrontation with teammate Vernon Maxwell.
Smith, in his mid-20s at the time, wanted to stop such behavior in its tracks, so he decided to make the team’s superstar aware of his boundaries early on.
Sometimes, for a relationship to truly break through, it first needs to hit a rough patch — and this perfectly describes the Olajuwon-Smith partnership. This is evident because, after their initial conflict, they went on to develop a strong bond.
It all began with Smith gradually making an effort to connect with the former Houston Cougar.
For instance, during bus rides, he noticed the seat next to Hakeem was always empty, so he started sitting there regularly to chat with the big man. One memorable trip, the two-time blocks leader shared a heartfelt moment, saying, ‘Kenny, you know you’re the first person that sits next to me and talks to me?'”
As a gesture of gratitude, Hakeem invited his new seat neighbor to break bread at his home. Smith accepted, brought his brother along, and the group enjoyed a fish dish prepared by “The Dream” himself. During that dinner, Hakeem shared his decision to recommit to Islam, and “The Jet” felt honored to be welcomed not only into his teammate’s home but also into his personal life. (Julian Eschenbach, Basketball Network, Jan 25 2025)
Related products
-
Duncan, Robert
A Selection of 65 Drawings from one drawing book 1952-1956
$400.00Black Sparrow Press: Los Angeles, 1970. 65 loose prints, not bound (as issued). A signed presentation copy from Duncan to Diane di Prima and her second husband Grant (Fisher), with a full page original drawing on card stock, measuring 6″ X 9″, in the style of drawings from the book. The Black Sparrow Press item appeared with a publisher’s chemise and signed colophon page — these are not present here and presumably weren’t included in the author’s copies of the book. A few minor age spots to card stock, otherwise fine. When speaking of the impact of Duncan’s teachings, di Prima cited the lesson that poetry intensifies life. In an interview with fellow Beat poet David Meltzer, she recalled, “Robert was probably one of the closest, most intimate lovers I ever had, even though we never had a physical relationship. I learned a lot of different kinds of things from him. One of the things I learned—in a way no teacher of Buddhism ever showed me—was how precious my life was. How precious the whole ambience of the time. A real sense of appreciating every minute.” di Prima recalled their personal relationship in an August 2001 interview with poet David Hadbawnik: “Robert used to come and hang for days, he’d move into my house in Marshall in the ’70s, and bring his French mysteries that he was teaching himself idiomatic French from, and his notebook, and he’d stay for days. And he always came to Christmases with the kids, because Jess doesn’t like holidays, and so I’d have to say mid-’70s, through ’75 on, he was there many weekends, many mornings…. Eating fried herring from the bay for breakfast.” less
moreOffered for Sale by: The Accidental Bookseller -
Hicks, J. R.
The Theory of Wages
$6,750.00London: Macmillan & Company, 1932. First edition of Hicks’ first book, an attempt at a careful and complete restatement of the marginal productivity theory. In the book, Hicks developed the microeconomics of wage determination in competitive and regulated labor markets. This work also introduced the famous concept of “elasticity of substitution” between capital and labor, which became his basis to dispute Karl Marx’s theory by arguing that labor-saving technological progress does not necessarily reduce labor’s share of income. The book became a standard textbook on labor economics for decades. Pasted in to rear is an autograph letter signed by Hicks to fellow economist Jacob Marschak. Circa 250 words over two-pages. Dear Marschak, I am sorry to have been so long before answering your letters. I certainly did not mean to imply that the elasticity of demand for labour being greater than one would be deemed a priori. The note on p. 100 is certainly badly expressed, especially as I did not really need this condition for my argument! But I was led into certain expression because I did feel convinced that the long run elasticity must be in fact > 1; and this for the reasons you suspect. I could not believe that the elasticity of supply of the other factors (long-period elasticities gains) were likely to be very negative – I should on the whole expect that their curves won’t be far from zero; and if this is so, the <mathematical expression> formula gives what seems a quite impossibly low value for σ if λ < 1. (This with a view to the Bowley calculation.) But I don’t nowadays put much confidence in all this. I think I should now approach the problem by regarding the <illegible> non-labour means of production as the “<illegible> factors whose elasticity of supply (ε), has to be considered. And I should bring in most of the “capital” complications (discovery, etc.) on the demand side. But this would probably mean a reconsideration of the “relative share” statistics. Anyway it is all rather vague. Yes, I agree that your diagram will <illegible> do. But I hope your research will throw more light on the question than (I am sure) mine has done. Autographed material from John Hicks is quite rare, and none of his letters, and few signed books, appear in book auction records. A very good copy lacking the scarce dust wrapper, spine tips rubbed, foxing to side of text block, weakness to the hinge between pages 96 & 97, and bookseller’s label from B. H. Blackwell of Oxford (Marschak, it should be noted, held positions at Oxford from 1930 – 1939). John R. Hicks received the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences (jointly with Kenneth J. Arrow) in 1972 for his pioneering contributions to general equilibrium theory and welfare theory. One of the most important and influential economists of the twentieth century, the trail of the eternally eclectic John Richard Hicks is found all over economic theory. Hicks made major contributions to many areas of 20th-century economics; four, in particular, stand out. First, he showed that, contrary to what Karl Marx had believed, labor-saving technological progress does not necessarily reduce labor’s share of the income. Second, he devised a diagram—the IS-LM diagram—that graphically depicts John M. Keynes’s conclusion that an economy can be in equilibrium with less-than-full employment. Third, through his book Value and Capital (1939), Hicks showed that much of what economists believe about value theory (the theory about why goods have value) can be reached without the assumption that utility is measurable. Fourth, he came up with a way to judge the impact of changes in government policy. He proposed a compensation test that could compare the losses for the losers with the gains for the winners. If those who gain could, in principle, compensate those who lose—even if they do not actually and directly compensate them—then, claimed Hicks, the change in policy would be efficient. “How is one to assess an economist whose legacy runs as wide and deep as that of John Hicks? The quintessential ‘economist’s economist’, Hicks cannot be said to have founded a ‘school’ – unless one were to count the generation of eclectic and critical Neo-Walrasian theorists inspired by his visionary but careful work, such as Morishima, Hahn and Negishi. But Hicks was for the most part a lone thinker, part of every school and thus part of no school. If any, his school was ‘economics’. Hicks himself claimed to have created no new economics but simply to have spent his life understanding, formulating and channeling the ideas of the Continental and Keynesian schools and his own historical, philosophical and practical reflections. In a sense, he may have been right – but he analyzed and extended them in a meaningful and challenging way and thus transformed economics in the process. In many ways, Hicks’s scholarly output is a perfect demonstration of how economics should be done: without partisanship for pet theories, without ideological quibbling, his own strictest critic, learning from all and everywhere, constantly searching for new ideas and staying glued to none. Hicks’s approach to economics was informed by all the best qualities of the scientist, poet, philosopher and practical man, and he let none of these tendencies overreach themselves and overwhelm any other. In this sense, no economist before or since Hicks, has achieved such ‘Olympian’ scholarship.” (The History of Economic Thought) The book is annotated in pencil, presumably by Marschak, with the summary “Assuming truth’s and half-truth’s with equal self confidence” written to the front free end paper. Jacob Marschak was an “important developer of economics information theory and a contributor to the early study of econometrics…Marschak’s major work was done in an obscure but important area of conceptual economic theory helping develop methodology for mathematical problem solving” (NY Times obituary). Not mentioned – because not known at the time – is that three of Marschak’s doctoral students went on to win the Nobel Prize for Economics: Leonid Hurwicz (2007), Harry Markowitz (1990) and Franco Modigliani (1985). Marschak was impressed by the need for quantification of economics. His 1931 paper on the elasticity of demand was a landmark in econometric analysis, and as head of the Cowles Commission from 1943 – 1948, Marschak can be given credit for getting the ball rolling for the development of Neo-Walrasian economics and econometrics in the post-war era. Marschak’s contributions to economic theory in this phase were dominated by his interest in the concept of uncertainty. Already in his classic 1938 papers (one with Helen Makower) on monetary theory, Marschak set down the basic ideas for portfolio theory, in which risk was acknowledged to play a role. His encounter with the work of John von Nemann and Oskar Morgenstern (1944) led him to write his famous 1950 exposition of the axiomatization of choice under uncertainty, when he introduced the infamous “independence axiom”. It was specifically in the theory of information, the theory of “teams” and decentralized organizations where Marschak was to make his name (1954, 1968, 1971, 1972). He is renowned for having developed the theory of stochastic design as a way of statistically measuring demand. It was Marschak who helped introduce modern information theory into economics via Shannon’s formalization of information via the mathematical theory of communication. Kenneth J. Arrow, himself a Nobelist, wrote “Marschak became a leader of research organizations at a relatively young age in Germany, and later—with his increasing recognition—was director of the Oxford Institute of Statistics (1935-1939) and of the Cowles Commission for Research in Economics at The University of Chicago (1943-1948)—a fertile period that greatly influenced the course of economic analysis in several diverse fields. Only after 1948 did he begin to make the contributions to economic analysis that are most distinctively his own. Yet in curious ways, the subject matter of his later studies was consonant with his earlier career. An organizer of economic research, he became a theorist of organization. A student and critic of new developments in economic analysis, he developed the economics of information. A skeptic distrustful of received dogma, he studied the economics of uncertainty. Another characteristic of Marschak’s work was his consistently interdisciplinary approach. Some of his early papers dealt with class structure and the emerging phenomenon of Italian fascism. From 1928 to about 1953, though his titles stayed more narrowly within the field of economics as it was then understood, the papers themselves not infrequently contained broader notions derived from politics, sociology, and—later—individual psychology. His work on information and organization, for example, led to a series of experimental and theoretical studies on the psychology of decision making, while during his last fifteen years he organized an interdisciplinary behavioral sciences seminar that proved a main source of contact among mathematical modelers with widely divergent interests.” less
moreOffered for Sale by: The Accidental Bookseller -
Hawkes, John (Author); Solien, T. L. (Artist).
Innocence in Extremis
$500.00New York: The Grenfell Press, 1985. From the colophon: “118 copies have been printed & published at The Grenfell Press, New York City, in spring/summer 1985. Copies numbered 1-85 are printed on Saunders paper and bound in quarter morocco with the covers and frontispiece by T. L. Solien. Roman numeral copies I-XV are bound in full morocco hand-colored by the artist and contain a frontispiece. Lettered copies A-R are for the author and artist. Bindings are by Claudia Cohen; Michael Bixler has set the text in Dante. Each copy has been signed by John Hawkes and T. L. Solien.” Copy XIII of the Roman numeral edition. T. L. Solien’s work has been the subject of numerous exhibitions across the country and is included in public and private collections around the world. Selected collections include: Metropolitan Museum of Art, Whitney Museum of American Art; Smithsonian American Art Museum; Art Institute of Chicago; Milwaukee Art Museum; Madison Museum of Contemporary Art; Minneapolis Institute of Art; Tate Gallery, London; National Gallery of Australia; Singapore Art Museum, among others. (source: Tory Folliard Gallery). Near fine, slight uneven tanning to boards, small and shallow abrasion to rear cover. In publisher’s plexiglass slipcase, one seam split as appears to be common to be this title, small chip and a couple of cracks, neither affecting the case’s integrity. less
moreOffered for Sale by: The Accidental Bookseller -
Lucien N-B Wyse
LE CANAL DE PANAMA L’Isthme Américain Explorations Comparaison Des Traces Étudiées Négociations Etat Des Travaux [SIGNED]
$406.73 *
* estimated currency conversionBound with Canal Interocéanique de Panama, Mission de 1890/1891 en Colombie, Rapport Général, Achille Heymann, 1891, Paris. Handsomely rebound set of Wyse’s two major works on the Panama Canal, both presentation copies and signed by him. Dedication to first blank dated May 1900, presenting the volume to the Bibliotheque Francaise in Syndey, Australia. The second work is more simply signed “Hommage de l’auteur – L N Bonaparte Wyse” to half title. There is a library stamp to each title page, but no other indications of library use. Three large fold out maps and plans present as required, along with fold-out table of the various plans and schemes submitted for the canal. First map has closed tear which has been effectively, if slightly crudely, repaired to rear, and all maps are a little grubby to creases. Now attractively rebound in green quarter leather with gilt tilting to spine and marbled paper-covered boards to match endpapers. Scare signed thus. French language. 4to. [6] 401pp [4] 154pp less
moreOffered for Sale by: Dodman Books